Sunday, February 5, 2012

Use These Proven Weight loss Tactics For The Best Results | New ...

New Health And Fitness.Org - Health Information You Can Use

Are you tired of being overweight? Despite being one of the most common health afflictions around today, being overweight does not have to be a permanent condition. Our tips will assist you lose weight and keep it off. The process can actually be quite simple, and by using these ideas, you?ll be convinced of that very fact.

A thorough daily housecleaning can help you drop some weight. Housecleaning has a side benefit of using oup extra calories, giving you a nice little workout in addition to your clean house. Some people have used music to keep up the tempo while cleaning.

Skipping breakfast can sabotage your weight loss efforts. Lots of people think that by skipping a meal, they ingest less calories. However, this is completely false. The fact is that your appetite is going to increase throughout the day if you don?t consume morning meal, and you?re ultimately going to consume a greater amount of meal and calories.

Dessert cravings are another thing to watch out for while dieting, however you do not have to deprive yourself of them. A few cravings are almost impossible to turn your back on. Angel meal cake is light and airy. Angel meal cakes are tasty and contain fewer calories than the most typical cakes.

Finding ways to pair your meals with physical workout will help your fat loss along. Are you going on a picnic? Walk to the closest park and have it there! If your schedule allows, planning to do some type of physical activity along with eating is an excellent way to keep your metabolic process going and workout the pounds away!

Attempt to use less condiments whenever you are topping your foods. These condiments have a lot of sugar and can add to the calorie content in your meal. Just use a tiny amount on top of your meal.

A great strategy in shedding pounds is to track your calories in a journal. If you do this, you?ll be likely to eat less. You could lose weight and maintain that loss by consuming a healthy diet.

There is no magic pill for fat burning. You have to change what you?re doing physically and tweak what you are putting into your body. If you?ll follow our tips, you?ll find success at effectively losing the weight that you need to lose and keeping it off.

Finding the best information about weight loss supplements can be overwhelming at times. One of the best places we found online to get the straight facts is purchase unique hoodia

Related Posts Plugin for WordPress, Blogger...

Source: http://newhealthandfitness.org/2012/02/05/use-these-proven-weight-loss-tactics-for-the-best-results/

rick perry gaffe rick perry gaffe graham spanier graham spanier penn state board of trustees brett ratner jerry sandusky

Children armed with assault weapons spark controversy in Venezuela

President Hugo Chavez has condemned photos of children posing with assault rifles at a pro-government group's event. But the opposition still blames Chavez.

? A version of this post ran on the author's blog, Insightcrime.com. The views expressed are the author's own.

Skip to next paragraph

Images of children armed with what look like assault weapons have sparked a heated debate in Venezuela over President Hugo Chavez?s support for armed militias in the country.

Colectivo La Piedrita is a pro-Chavez group based in western Caracas which bills itself as a community political organization but which Chavez himself has previously denounced (in Spanish). On January 23, La Piedrita celebrated the anniversary of the end of the dictatorship of Marcos Perez Jimenez in 1958.

This week, photos emerged which appear to have been taken at the event and posted on the group?s Facebook page, showing children carrying M-16 assault rifles. The children are wearing bandanas and seated in front of a mural depicting Jesus and the Virgin Mary holding Kalashnikovs. Other photos, seemingly from the same event, suggest that Venezuelan congressman Robert Serra was present, indicating some level of official support for the display.

The release of the photos caused something of a political firestorm in Venezuela. Potential presidential opposition politician Pablo Perez (in Spanish) criticized the photos, saying: "Instead of guns, these children should have a computer, a book, a bat, a ball, a glove, or a musical instrument."

The Chavez administration itself has condemned the images, with Interior Minister Tarek El-Aissami calling them ?morally reprehensible" (in Spanish).

Diego Arria, another strong opponent of Chavez, criticized the president via Twitter, claiming that the President only distanced himself from the photos because they were distributed so widely.

For his part, Serra has said that the photos taken of the children were taken at a separate event in November, which he did not attend. Meanwhile, Colectivo La Piedrita claims that the rifles were made of plastic (in Spanish), and were part of a skit meant to commemorate the demobilization of guerrilla groups in the country during the 1960s. The children allegedly handed over toy rifles in exchange for copies of the Constitution.

InSight Crime Analysis

The incident draws attention to the highly politicized nature of Venezuelan society. Ever since Chavez took office, the discourse used by his supporters and detractors has become extremely polarized. Chavez has not helped this issue by arming civilian militias for political purposes, which may have contributed to the rise in street violence in the country.

The sight of small children with guns in their hand, real or not, touches on the broader issue of youth violence in Venezuela. As InSight Crime has reported, guns are widely available among poor youths in the country, and gun violence disproportionately affects those between 15 and 29 years old.

--- Geoffrey Ramsey ?is a writer for Insight ? Organized Crime in the Americas, which provides research, analysis, and investigation of the criminal world throughout the region. Find all of his research here.

Get daily or weekly updates from CSMonitor.com delivered to your inbox.?Sign up today.

The Christian Science Monitor has assembled a diverse group of Latin America bloggers. Our guest bloggers are not employed or directed by the Monitor and the views expressed are the bloggers' own, as is responsibility for the content of their blogs. To contact us about a blogger, click here.

Source: http://rss.csmonitor.com/~r/feeds/csm/~3/Jjq6a7sD1vY/Children-armed-with-assault-weapons-spark-controversy-in-Venezuela

gabrielle union mark wahlberg ladainian tomlinson merle haggard apple announcement yu darvish keystone xl

Saturday, February 4, 2012

Possible Free Accounting Software for Your Business | Author ...

Due t? extreme competition ?n th? business world, ?t become very tough task t? r?n ?n? business successfully. It requires efficient ?nd intelligent business workers t? manage ?t well. Accounting software ??n exactly d? th?t f?r ???. It ??n provide ??? th? solution regarding t? management difficulties related t? accounts ?nd finance. Getting th? software b? downloading th?m free ?f cost ?? g??d thing. Free accounting software saves abundant amount ?f ???r wealth along w?th valued time. Saved wealth ??n b? fruitfully utilized ?n various ?th?r arenas ?f th? business. Y?? ?r? well known ?b??t accounting, financial ?nd ?b??t various payroll services associated w?th a business. Although th?? ?? n?t possible t? keep track ?f ?ll services until th? tracking procedure ?? extremely mechanized.

Free accounting software lessens number ?f errors wh??h ?r? bound t? occur wh?l? managing th? accounts manually.

Accounting software l?k? saas offers ??? w?th account payable module wh??h helps ??? t? pay th? bills easily, products ??r?h???? ?nd paying vendors ?n th? same time. Account receivable module allows analyzing various reports ?n th? ?th?r hand. It particularly helps th? company t? amend th??r policies ?nd marketing strategies, wh?n necessary. It ?l?? avails t? endow w?th general ledger wh??h ??n b? used t? keep a track ?f ?ll th? transactions ?nd divided ?nt? five categories wh??h ?r? known ?? assets, liabilities, equity, revenue ?nd expenses. It ?? ?l?? easy t? maintain pay periods ?nd wages ?f ?ll th? workers b? th? ??? ?f payroll application ?f th? ecommerce software. Free accounting software h??? a variety ?f traits ?? ?t ?? quite effortless t? bring ?nt? play, tough ?nd multiuser prop up wh?r? a lot ?f users ??n exploit th? software ?n tandem.

On th? ?th?r hand account receivable module allows ??? t? analyze various reports wh??h ??n tend t? formulate various useful future plans f?r th? business.

Th?? software particularly helps t? amend th? company along w?th required policies ?nd marketing strategies. It ?l?? offers th? facility ?f general ledger wh?r? one ??n keep track ?f ?ll th? transactions wh??h ?? divided ?nt? five uppermost categories usually known ?? assets, equity, expenses, revenues ?nd liabilities. Now ?t becomeseasier t? maintain pay periods ?nd wages ?f ?ll workers b? th? h?l? ?f payroll application ?f th? ecommerce software.Accounting software helps ??? t? m?k? ???r business fruitful ?nd ?t ?? quite easy t? ??? ?nd ??n b? used b? users ?t th? same time ??.

Related Post

You can leave a response, or trackback from your own site.

Source: http://authoradvanced.com/possible-free-accounting-software-for-your-business.html

cmas cmas world series of poker joe walsh zsa zsa gabor heavy d dead heavy d dead

Learn to Ice Skate Toronto Private Skating Lessons Toronto Canada ...

All figure skaters fall down, even he very best. When figure skaters begin to learn new jumps or spins, they may fall hundreds of times. If a skater falls in an ice skating competition, points are deducted.

If You Are Going to Skate, You Are Going to Fall:

?

If you are a figure skater, you must understand that if you are going to skate, you are going to fall. That's a fact. Practicing falling over and over again is the only way to learn how to fall safely.

How To Fall On the Ice Without Getting Hurt:

?

It may help to practice falling when you are off the ice. Then, practice falling on the ice from a standstill, then while moving slowly, and then while moving more quickly. Wearing gloves may help.

?

Don't Lean Backward:

?

If you anticipate a fall, do not lean backward, but try to move your body and head forward. Relax. Do not stiffen up; allow your body to go limp.

?

More Falling Tips:

?

Beginning ice skaters can practice falling from a dip position.

To do a dip, first glide forward on two feet and squat down as far as possible. Fall to the side and lean a bit forward. Do not lean back, or you may hit your head. Put your hands in your lap and not on the ice. If you leave your hands on the ice, another skater could skate over your fingers!

?

Don't Cry When You Fall Down:

?

All figure skaters should remember that falling down is part of our sport. If possible, avoid crying after a fall.

In addition, the skater should return to the ice as soon as possible and do the move on which the fall occurred.

?

The skater should remember to get up from a fall as soon as possible. Remaining sitting or lying on the ice poses a danger to both the skater and to others. It is important to get up quickly.

?

Serious Figure Skating Falls:

?

Ice dancing falls can be dangerous, but pair skating falls can be more serious.

At the 2006 Olympic Games, Dan Zhang fell as the team attempted a throw quadruple Salchow. The crowd gasped. She doubled over in pain, and it seemed that the team's Olympics were finished. Instead, she recovered; the team returned to the ice and completed their program. The pair won the Olympic silver medal.

?

Zhang's story is a happy one, but in the late 1990s, Paul Binnebose, a pair skater, was seriously injured from a fall. He was practicing a lift with his partner when he fell backward and hit his head on the ice. That injury nearly cost him his life. He did not compete again but did continue in the sport as a coach.

?

Pair skating at one time was more graceful than athletic. It did require some risks, but it was not considered as dangerous as it is today. Skaters were rarely thrown through the air or held upside down. Things were not done at the high speed required for today's athletic moves. Even though pair skating was safer at that time than it is now, falls did occur, as they do in all branches of figure skating.

?

Figure Skaters That Fall Down Can Still Win:

?

At a figure skating competition, each move in an ice skater's program equals certain points. For example, a triple jump is many more points than a double jump.

?

Spectators can see what they think is a "perfect program," but if the competitor doesn't have elements in their routine that will get high points, a skater can place behind someone who attempted jumps and spins that are awarded higher scores. This means that even if a skater falls down and makes obvious errors, that a skater with a flawless program can place behind a skater that falls.

?

Source: http://genecast.com/Sports/learn-to-ice-skate-toronto-private-skating-lessons-toronto-canada-32052.html

road conditions weather gina carano al green at last burger king delivery etta james at last

Friday, February 3, 2012

Inboxhawk ? Different Types Of Vehicle Leasing Solutions

It is absolutely true fact hat these days vehicle leasing is becoming a very popular solution to lending to buying a business vehicle, but it can be a very beneficial solution for individuals as well. Every time you desire to buy a car or even simply rent some auto for a short period of time, vehicle leasing options could be the relevant answer.

It includes renting an automobile, similar to the facilities of leasing a house or an office. When opting for car lease, the finance company gets the automobile of your choice. They then give you a possibility you to use that automobile for the period of the lease in return for a payment that is to be covered per month.

If the automobile is used only for business needs, the repayments charged are completely tax deductible when automobile leasing. It included such issues as renting a depreciation which is your tax deduction.
Benefits
Some of the advantages of vehicle leasing are:
1. Rates can be a tax deduction for vehicles hired for business
2. Car leasing enables you to change your automobile every several years
3. Interest and monthly fees are fixed, so rates are known beforehand
4. Payments are generally considerably lower than a vehicle loan
5. The automobile is used as security against the car lease, so you may expect that the interest rates are normally much lower than automobile loans
6. They provide clients with pretty flexible terms from 2 to 5 years
7. You may get both brand new or used vehicles.

Types of car lease options available
1. operating vehicle leases,
2. finance vehicle leases
3. novated vehicle leases.
It is worth mentioning that the basic difference between finance and operating car lease facilities is at the end of the vehicle leasing term. In the case you opt for an operating lease, the lease lender retains ownership of the automobile leased, whereas in the event of finance leasing, the customer is required to pay out the balloon or residual fees and the client is to assume his ownership. Some issues at the end of a finance vehicle lease are as the following ones: pay out the balloon payment and have the car, trade in the automobile, or refinance the residual payment with some other automobile lease or loan.

It is necessary to admit that a fully maintained automobile lease is a finance leasing option that includes running rates of the car such as different services, tyres fuel, and so on and so forth. This type of automobile leasing is great if you need to have some fixed costs every month.

Novated vehicle leasing works rather differently to finance and operating solutions. In the event you are an employee wanting leasing a car, you are recommended to consider novated vehicle leasing if you desire to salary package an automobile.

Both comments and pings are currently closed.

Source: http://inboxhawk.com/2012/02/02/different-types-of-vehicle-leasing-solutions/

south carolina debate nightline lauren scruggs william shatner seattle weather skier sarah burke gingrich wife

Viacom 1Q earnings shredded by 'Rock Band' (AP)

NEW YORK ? Viacom Inc., the owner of Paramount Pictures, MTV and Comedy Central, on Thursday posted a 65 percent drop in net income for the latest quarter, as it took a charge related to the "Rock Band" series of video games.

Revenue was below analyst estimates, sending its stock down.

Viacom earned $212 million, or 38 cents per share, in the October-December quarter, down from $610 million, or $1 per share, a year ago.

The New York-based company took a charge of $379 million to cover an arbitration award won by the original shareholders of Harmonix Music Systems Inc., which created "Rock Band."

The game let players take "Guitar Hero" one step further by connecting a drum-kit and a microphone to a game console, along with a guitar, and play and sing along to songs. It was hit when it came out in 2007, but its popularity faded quickly, along with that of "Guitar Hero."

Viacom had acquired Harmonix in 2006, but sold it back to its founders in 2010. The founders then sued, claiming that they were owed extra payments for the performance of "Rock Band" during its spell of popularity. They won an arbitration award of $383 million in December. Viacom is contesting it, but has set aside the money to cover the award, reflected in the charge to earnings.

Excluding the "Rock Band" charge, earnings were $1.06 per share in its fiscal first quarter, a penny above the average analyst estimate as polled by FactSet.

Operating income fell 2 percent as expenses outpaced revenue, which rose 3 percent to $3.95 billion from $3.83 billion. Analysts expected $3.99 billion.

Viacom's B shares fell $2.53, or 5.4 percent, to $44.44 in premarket trading.

Results at Paramount were stable, as strong box-office results from "Paranormal Activity 3" and "Mission Impossible ? Ghost Protocol" offset a drop in ancillary revenue.

For the TV networks, results were buoyed an increase in fees from cable companies, while advertising, the largest single source of revenue, decline 3 percent.

Source: http://us.rd.yahoo.com/dailynews/rss/earnings/*http%3A//news.yahoo.com/s/ap/20120202/ap_on_hi_te/us_earns_viacom

blow i am legend bret michaels bret michaels the unit bob weston david wilson

Thursday, February 2, 2012

Mesothelioma And Carcinoma Of The Lung - Listen to Fraser

Asbestos fibers And Carcinoma Of The Lung

Asbestos fibers and carcinoma of the lung, of course it?s true that asbestos is really a primary reason for the true reason for this lethal illness. Just before we appraise the interrelationship among asbestos fiber and cancer of the lung you need to know precisely what is asbestos fiber and precisely what are its Asbestosis Compensation health implications.Lung Mesothelioma

What is actually Asbestos fiber?

Asbestos is often a naturally sourced spring as enclosed products. Asbestos fibers components are heat and Effects of Lung Cancer chemical tolerant and are generally Asbestos Poisoning weak conductor of electric power. These characteristics allow it to be healthy for business use. Companies use some forms of Asbestos fibers: Chrysolite or light asbestos fiber, Crocidolite or orange mesothelioma, Anthophyllite or grey coloured components and Amosite or brown leafy tinted supplies. These mesothelioma products enter in tiny dust contaminants and thus effortlessly taken in or ingested that could trigger severe well being disorders. Carcinoma of the lung brought on from asbestos fibers is really a these kinds of illustration.Effects of Lung Cancer

Health Threats of Asbestos fibers

Frequent contact with asbestos may result in numerous considerable ailments as an example carcinoma of the lung, mesothelioma cancer melanoma and asbestosis. Asbestosis is usually as lung ailment which causes difficulty breathing, breathing problems and long lasting injury to bronchi and Mesothelioma cancer cancer-an uncommon cancer malignancy of tissue layer since the chest muscles and tummy, and cancer of larynx, oropharynx, large intestine and help.

Regular coverage of mesothelioma leads to work Symptoms of lung cancer ailments as an example united states and mesothelioma melanoma. Considering that 1940, plenty of American staff members, utilized in shipbuilding organizations, exploration and mincing of asbestos fiber, creation of asbestos fiber linens together with other asbestos objects, heat retaining material in design and building investments, and braking system restoration have been Mesothelioma life expectancy found to asbestos fiber. Demolition employees, drywall removal and firefighters also are prone to staying uncovered to mesothelioma that could result in united states included.

Because of rigid norms that has been enhanced operate practices, present day employees confront minimum possible risks with carcinoma of the lung from asbestos fiber. Although bulkier and lengthier coverage time is attributed for your risk but scientists found out that small exposures may also result in an infection. Not just your staff but their loved ones are prone to mesothelioma health problems and cancer of the lung. Para operate subjection happens because asbestos Mesothelioma Lawsuit Compensation resources are presented into the property through sneakers, Asbestos Injury apparel, skin and hair of staff. You need to coverage employees are necessary to look at shower and alter their apparel previous to leaving behind their office.

The difficult a part of mesothelioma associated illnesses and asbestos fiber relevant united states is they can lay inactive in your body for 10-forty years prior to starting. This helps it be challenging to determine the trouble carrying on. When the ailments are revealed and determined, it is far too late and chances of emergency of patients are incredibly gloomy.

Published on February 2, 2012 ? Filed under: Uncategorized;

Source: http://listentofraser.com/?p=1289

work it jerry angelo amy chua iowa gop gloria steinem forgetting sarah marshall meteor shower tonight

Whale acrobatics inspire a faster helicopter

Paul Marks, senior technology correspondent

Image: Tiny rubber bumps, akin to whale fin nodules, attached to the rotor blade (Credit: DLR)The way the humpback whale, Megaptera novaeangliae, manages to perform underwater acrobatics and turn on a dime - despite having pendulous, outsize pectoral fins - has inspired aviation engineers in G?ttingen, Germany to make a faster, quieter helicopter rotor blade.A helicopter has a rotor whose aerofoil-shaped blades provides lift, directional control and forward thrust. As the rotor spins, the advancing blade - which is moving in the same direction as the craft - is travelling faster than the retreating blade on the opposite side. These different speeds make for turbulence, vibration and instability - especially during fast flight and whilst turning, when the retreating blade is more likely to lose lift and "stall". As a result, helicopter engineers spend a lot of time trying to minimise this effect.Noting the humpback's agility in water, Kai Richter and colleagues at the German Aerospace Centre (DLR) wondered if something analagous to the bumps on its pectoral fins - known to provide lift underwater and boost the creature's buoyancy - could help them improve chopper design. Scaling those bumps down relative to a rotor's width, they made 6-millimetre-diameter rubber grommets and fastened 186 of them? to the leading edges of the rotors on a test helicopter (see picture, above).?It did indeed significantly delay stalling and the difference has already been noticed by test pilots, Kai says, providing a smoother ride. They have been encouraged enough by their results to file patents on the idea, and they now plan further tests. If their whale mimicry pans out, it won't involve clunky rubber grommets: the bumps would be milled into blades during manufacturing.The humpback whale: agile despite its size (Credit: DLR) Subscribe to New Scientist Magazine

Source: http://feeds.newscientist.com/c/749/f/10897/s/1c4ced8f/l/0L0Snewscientist0N0Cblogs0Conepercent0C20A120C0A10Cwhale0Eacrobatics0Einspire0Ea0Ego0E0Bhtml0DDCMP0FOTC0Erss0Gnsref0Fonline0Enews/story01.htm

red hook oscar nominees the tree of life movie 2012 oscar nominations academy award nominees 2012 florida debate kyle williams

Wednesday, February 1, 2012

Kristen Bell Ellen Video Is The Funniest Thing I?ve Seen All Week

Kristen Bell appeared on Ellen where she revealed her slot obsession and her freaky intuition when a slot was near on her birthday. Check it out here. Ok so this is seriously the funniest thing I have seen all week. Kristen Bell cracked me up. The story is funny enough, but then she brought the video from the actual event and it took it to another level. Tears people, real tears. Check out the video below and then enjoy my other links? New video by Lil Wayne f/ Bruno Mars ?Mirror? – DIVA ARTIST. Sarah Jessica Parker And Her Baby Enduring The Cold — GOSSIP AND SOAPS. Selena Gomez Talks About Her Love For Justin Bieber in Cosmopolitan – HAVE U HEARD. New Couple Alert: Elisabetta Canalis and Steve-O – LICKABLE CELEBS. 55 Hottest Celebrity Men To Lust After ? – ALL WOMEN STALK. Keira Knightley Covers GQ UK March 2012 – AMY GRINDHOUSE. Basketball Wives Season 4 Trailer Couldn’t Be More Over The Top – POPT Jennifer Lopez Dishes On Her Divorce During Interview With Matt Lauer – DAILY STAB. Photos: www.wenn.com/Apega

Source: http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/RightCelebrity/~3/FJSdz1JJcZc/

lemony snicket jim thome jim thome fun fun fun fest fun fun fun fest move your money robert schuller

Fama on Finance | EconTalk | Library of Economics and Liberty

Eugene Fama of the University of Chicago talks with EconTalk host Russ Roberts about the evolution of finance, the efficient market hypothesis, the current crisis, the economics of stimulus, and the role of empirical work in finance and economics.

Right-click or Option-click, and select "Save Link/Target As MP3.

Readings and Links related to this podcast

About this week's guest: About ideas and people mentioned in this podcast:
    Articles: Podcasts and Blogs:

Highlights

Time
0:36Intro. [Recording date: January 17, 2012.] Russ: Your impact on the field of finance has been immense--in a whole bunch of areas, but one that stands out is the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH). I'd like you to sketch out the evolution of that idea in the field, how it was understood initially, and how it has changed over time. Guest: How much time do we have? Russ: Well, four or five hours, but let's try to keep it to under 10 minutes for this first question, if you can. Guest: Okay. I'll go back to the beginning. The way Harry Roberts tells it, Holbrook Working in the 1930s started to become interested in whether speculative prices moved randomly. He was mostly an agricultural economist, looking at agricultural commodities, and he took a series of random numbers, simulated them, and brought them to his faculty at Stanford, faculty lounge, I guess; showed them to them and they agreed they were an agricultural series. So he thought from that that maybe a random walk kind of model would work pretty well for agricultural prices, prices of other commodities. But then there was a big gap from there to like the end of the 1950s. And what opened things up was the coming of computers, which made computations much easier. And the most readily available data was stock price data. So, basically, statisticians, econometricians took the data and started doing calculations on it, calculating autocorrelations with their estimates of how predictable returns are based on past returns. And then they stopped. Economists got into the mix and said: Okay, how would we expect prices to behave if they were set based on all available information? Which is basically the EMH, but it wasn't stated in those terms at that time. So, they said: I think they should be a random walk, an hypothesis pulled out of the air. Russ: When you say it's a random walk, explain what that means. Guest: That means that expected changes are successive changes are independent of one another. It also means they have identical distributions, but that part is not important. It's basically the independence part that's important. It basically means that you can't predict future returns based on past returns. Russ: And yesterday doesn't tell you anything about tomorrow. Guest: Right. Returns from day to day are basically independent of past returns. Now that was a very extreme hypothesis. Let me give you an example. You wouldn't say that about tomatoes, for example. Tomatoes are going to be cheaper in August than in January, for the most part, because they are seasonal. It has to do with supply and demand--mostly supply of tomatoes. There's a similar thing operating in prices of stocks, bonds, whatever. Basically, there's an expected return component, what people would require in order to hold those securities; and there's no reason that that has to be independent through time. There's no reason why that's not predictable or why it doesn't go--and there's lots of evidence that it is--higher on stocks during recessions and lower during good times. So there can be predictability in returns that is consistency with efficient markets. What people didn't understand in the beginning was that propositions about how prices should behave had to be joined to a statement about how you think they ought to behave. In other words, what you need is some statement about what we call a market equilibrium. What is the risk-return model you have in mind underlying the behavior of the prices in returns? So, for example, stocks are very risky; they require a higher expected return than bonds; and you have to take that into account in the tests. So there is this, what I call the joint hypothesis problem, which is basically what I added to the mix, but it's kind of an important part of it. It says whenever you are testing market efficiency you are jointly testing efficiency with some story about risk and return. And the two are joined at the hip. You can't separate them. So, people infer from that, it means market efficiency is not testable on its own. And that's true. But the reverse is also true. A risk-return model is untestable without market efficiency. Most risk-return models assume that markets are efficient. With very few exceptions.
6:18Russ: And so when we say markets are efficient, what do you mean by that? Guest: What you mean is that prices at any point in time reflect all available information. Russ: Now that idea--what's the distinction between the weak form and the strong form that people talk about? Guest: Two words that I used in 1970 that I came to regret. Because I was trying to categorize various tests that were done. So, I called weak form tests, tests that only used past prices and returns to predict future prices and returns. And I called semi-strong form tests, tests that used other kinds of public information to predict returns, like an earnings announcement or something like that. And then I called strong form tests, tests that look at all available information; and those are basically tests of if you look at groups of investment managers and you look at returns that they generate, you are basically looking at all the information they had to generate to [?] securities, and what's the evidence that the information they had wasn't in prices. Russ: And empirically, where do we stand today, do you believe and what has been established about those various hypotheses? Guest: Well, believe it or not, the weak form one has been the one that has been subject to the most, what people call anomalies, in finance. Things that are inconsistent with either market efficiency or some model of risk and return. The big one at the moment is what people call momentum--prices seem to move in the same direction for short periods of time. So, the winners of last year tend to be winners for a few more months, and the losers tend to be losers for a few more months. In the strong form tests, Ken French and I just published a paper called "Luck Versus Skill in Mutual Fund Performance," and basically looked at performance of the whole mutual fund industry--in the aggregate, together, and fund by fund, and try to distinguish to what extent returns are due to luck versus skill. And the evidence basically says the tests it's skill in the extreme. But you've got skill in both extremes. That's something people have trouble accepting. But it comes down to a simple proposition, which is that active management in trying to pick stocks has to be a zero sum game, because the winners have to win at the expense of losers. And that's kind of a difficult concept. But it shows up when you look at the cross section of mutual fund returns, in other words the returns for all funds over very long periods of time. What you find is, if you give them back all their costs, there are people in the left tail that look too extreme and there are people in the right tail that look too extreme, and the right tail and left tail basically offset each other. If you look at the industry as a whole; the industry basically holds a market portfolio. That's all before costs. If you look at returns to investors then there is no evidence that anybody surely has information sufficient to cover their costs.
10:11Russ: Which says that for any individual investing, certainly someone like me, that is, who doesn't spend any time or very much time at all looking--in my case no time, but let's suppose even a little time--trying to look at what would be a good investment. The implication is to go with index mutual funds because actively managed funds can't outperform. Guest: Well, no, it's more subtle than that. What's more subtle about it is, even if you spent time, you are unlikely to be able to pick the funds that will be successful because so much of what happens is due to chance. Russ: So, for me the lesson is: buy index mutual funds because the transaction costs of those are the smallest, and since very few actively managed funds can generate returns with any expectation other than chance to overcome those higher costs, I can make more money with an index fund. Guest: Right. Now, it's very counterintuitive, because we look at the whole history of every fund's returns, and sort them, and really the ones in the right tail are really extreme. Russ: Some great ones. Guest: They beat their benchmarks by 3-6% a year. Nevertheless, only 3% of them do about as well as you would expect by chance. Now what's subtle there is that by chance, with 3000-plus funds, you expect lots of them to do extremely well over their whole lifetime. So, these are the people that books get written about. Russ: Because they look smart. Guest: What this basically says is that there is a pretty good chance they are just lucky. And they had sustained periods of luck--which you expect in a big sample of funds. Russ: Of course, they don't see it that way. Guest: No, of course not. Russ: A friend of mine who is a hedge fund manager--before I made this call I asked him what he would ask you, and he said, well, his assessment is that efficient markets explain some tiny proportion of volatility of stock prices but there's still plenty of opportunity for a person to make money before markets adjust. And of course in doing so, make that adjustment actually happen and bring markets to equilibrium. Somebody has to provide the information or act on the information that is at least public and maybe only semi-public. What's your reaction to that comment? Guest: That's the standard comment from an active manager. It's not true. Merton Miller always liked to emphasize that you could have full adjustment to information without trading. If all the information were available at very low cost, prices could adjust without any trading taking place. Just bid-ask prices. So, it's not true that somebody has to do it. But the issue is--this goes back to a famous paper by Grossman and Stiglitz--the issue really is what is the cost of the information? And I have a very simple model in mind. In my mind, information is available, available at very low cost, then the cost function gets very steep. Basically goes off to infinity very quickly. Russ: And therefore? Guest: And therefore prices are very efficient because the information that's available is costless. Russ: But what's the implication of that steep incline? That information is not very-- Guest: It doesn't pay to try to take advantage of additional information. Russ: It's not very valuable. Guest: No, it's very valuable. If you were able to perfectly predict the future, of course that would be very valuable. But you can't. It becomes infinitely costly to do that. Russ: So, your assessment, that you just gave me of the state of our knowledge of this area, I would say remains what it's been for some time--that at the individual certainly there is no return to--prices reflect all publicly available information for practical purposes for an individual investor. Guest: For an individual investor? Even for an institutional investor. Russ: Correct. So, what proportion of the economics and finance areas do you think agree with that? Guest: Finance has developed quite a lot in the last 50 years that I've been in it. I would say the people who do asset pricing--portfolio theory, risk and return--those people think markets are pretty efficient. If you go to people in other areas who are not so familiar with the evidence in asset pricing, well, then there is more skepticism. I attribute that to the fact that finance, like other areas of economics, have become more specialized. And people just can't know all the stuff that's available. Russ: Sure. Guest: There's an incredible demand for market inefficiency. The whole investment management business is based on the idea that the market is not efficient. I say to my students when they take my course: If you really believe what I say and go out and recruit and tell people you think markets are efficient, you'll never get a job. Russ: Yes, it's true. And so there's a certain bias, you are saying, to how people assess the evidence. Guest: There's a bias. The bias is based, among professional money managers, the bias comes from the fact that they make more money from portraying themselves as active managers. Russ: That's true in macroeconomics as well. We'll get to that a little later in the conversation.
16:50Russ: I was going to ask you about the current crisis. Guest: I have some unusual views on that, too. Russ: I'd say that the mainstream view--and I recently saw a survey that said--it was an esteemed panel of economists; you weren't on it but it was still esteemed, both in finance and out of finance. And they asked them whether prices reflected information and there was near unanimity. Some strongly agreed; some just agreed. But there was also near unanimity that the housing market had been a bubble. Guest: The nasty b-word. Russ: Yes; and was showing some form of what we might call irrationality. Guest: Okay, so they had strong feelings about that, getting mad about the word bubble. Russ: Why? Guest: Because I think people see bubbles with 20-20 hindsight. The term has lost its meaning. It used to mean something that had a more or less predictable ending. Now people use it to mean a big swing in prices, that after the fact is wrong. But all prices changes after the fact are wrong. Because new information comes out that makes what people thought two minutes ago wrong two minutes later. Housing bubble--if you think there was a housing bubble, there might have been; if you had predicted it, that would be fine; but the reality is, all markets did the same thing at the same time. So you have to really face that fact that if you think it was a housing bubble, it was a stock price bubble, it was a corporate bond bubble, it was a commodities bubble. Are economists really willing to live with a world where there are bubbles in everything at the same time? Russ: And your explanation then of that phenomenon? Guest: My explanation is you had a big recession. I think you can explain almost everything just by saying you had a big recession. A really big recession. Russ: And why do you think we had a really big recession? Guest: I've heard some of your podcasts; I'm with you. I don't think macroeconomists have ever been good at knowing why we have recessions. We still don't understand the Great Depression. Russ: True. Although Ben Bernanke would argue, and Milton Friedman would argue and he did before he passed away, that monetary policy is a huge part of it. Guest: Let me reflect. I had this discussion with Milton, actually; and what I pointed out was from your own data, they show that there were massive free reserves throughout the Great Depression. And my point is: we can't force people to move demand deposits. Or to make love to anyone. Russ: Well, you can but it's not very productive. Guest: It's not very productive. M1 and M2--those things are basically endogenous. Russ: I have the same feeling. Guest: The only thing that's sort of exogenous is the monetary base. Russ: What did Milton say to that? Guest: All I gathered from Milton was: Interesting. Even when you won you thought you lost. Russ: Yes, I know. I had plenty of those. So, are you saying that that's analogous to our current situation? Guest: Oh, no. What I'm saying is that for example people want to blame the recession on the housing sector crashing and subprime mortgages. But if you are an economist and you are thinking about that, you have to be saying that there was some misallocation across markets, that margins weren't being equated across markets. That's pretty hard to accept because people are acting in all markets, working in all markets. That's a pretty tough one to follow. Russ: Well, a lot of people swallow it. Here's their version. They say things like there are these things called animal spirits that you can't measure, but that doesn't mean they are not real; that people get all excited about a particular asset class--in this case it was housing. And as those prices start to rise it becomes rational to speculate that it will continue to rise. And as that happens--as you would admit, people are making money along the way--and then they don't. They stop making money; the prices collapse. And this happens from time to time because of irrational exuberance; and that's just an aspect of capitalism. That's the standard counterpoint. Guest: Okay, but it wasn't just housing. That was my point when we started. The same thing was going on in all asset markets. Russ: Well, the timing isn't quite identical for all asset markets, right? The stock market--the housing market starts to collapse I think around early-mid-2006. Guest: It stops rising, right. Russ: And then begins a steady decline. Guest: That decline was nothing compared to the stock market decline. Russ: But when did that happen? Guest: I don't know the exact timing. Russ: It's not around then. It's later. Guest: The onset of the recession started with the collapse of the stock market. The recession and the collapse of the stock market, the corporate bond market, all of that basically coincides. But that also coincides with the collapse of the securitized bond market. Russ: Mortgage-backed securities. Guest: The subprime mortgages and all of that. Russ: Well, yes; that happens through 2007, 2008. I guess there is some parallel. So, you are going to reverse the causation. Guest: I'm not saying I know. What I'm saying is I can tell the whole story just based on the recession. And I don't think you can come up with evidence that contradicts that. But I'm not saying I know I'm right. I don't know. I'm just saying people read the evidence through a narrow lens. Russ: Yes, they do. Confirmation bias. Guest: And the rhetoric acquires a life of its own; so there are books written that basically all say the same thing about the crisis. Russ: And you are arguing that they have essentially cherry-picked the data. Guest: Well, they just look at pieces of the data and the fact that the housing market collapsed is taken to be the cause; but the housing market could collapse for other reasons. People don't just decide that prices aren't high any more. They have to look at supply and demand somewhere in the background. Russ: We did have people holding second and third homes who didn't have the income and capability of repaying the first one. Guest: Sure. Standards were relaxed. But then you have to look on the supply side, the lending side. The people who were lending to these people had the information. Russ: Yes, they knew it. I don't think that they were fooled. They were not overly optimistic about the value of those loans. They were willing to do that because they could sell them. Guest: The puzzle is why they were able to sell them.
24:17Russ: Correct. Now my claim is the people who bought them did it with largely borrowed money. Guest: No, that's not true. These were bought by people all over the world. Russ: Correct. Guest: No one borrowed money. Remember now: savings has to equal lending. For everyone that's short bonds, somebody is on the other side. The net amount of leverage in the world is always zero. Russ: That's true. Guest: So you can't tell a story based on leverage. Russ: So what's your story? I have to think that through. It's undeniably true, and I'm not going to argue with that point. So, what's your explanation of why people bought these things? Guest: Well, I have no explanation. Again, I'd say the market crashes because of the big recession. Even a minor depression if you like. Remember that all the people buying these subprime mortgages all over the world, they are the ones making the loans in the end, they were sophisticated investors. Institutions, big banks all over the world. They thought these things were appropriately priced. They might have been at that time, but they weren't ex post. Russ: So you are not going to allow me to make the claim that the incentives they faced to worry about how appropriately priced were distorted. Guest: The incentives to make money are always there. The question is whether the market lets you make money. So, these people that wanted to securitize all these mortgages, they could have failed at any time in the process; and they would have failed big time because in order to do these things, you have to initially finance them yourself. So when the investment bankers were bringing out the securitized mortgages and other kinds of securitized assets, they initially held them. And they held them afterwards, too. Russ: They held many of them. Guest: Well, initially they held them all, because they are bundling them together; they have to come up with the capital and then they can sell them. So, they could have failed right at that point because the market says: Forget it. We're not paying you par value for these things. Russ: But when they did fail, which they fundamentally did because, at least for them, even though the world wasn't leveraged, they were leveraged, they should have gone out of business. Guest: Right, exactly. Russ: But they did not. Guest: That's awful. That's the worst consequence of this whole episode. Russ: So, my narrative is the anticipation of that distorted their decision-making. Guest: Sure, but that doesn't satisfy what address what goes on on the demand side. Russ: Why? Guest: Because people on the demand side have to buy these things. Russ: Well, the people who were buying them, and selling them, were fundamentally the same people, right? Guest: Okay, so if greed causes me to put out securities that I know are no good, why would I hold them? Russ: Because I can hold them at a very low cost. I have uncertainty; I don't know what's going to happen. There's an upside; there's a downside. Guest: It's really a low cost if you know you are going to get bailed out. Russ: Right. My argument is it dulls your senses. Guest: It does; I agree with you there. Any probability that you are going to be bailed out is going to distort your decision. Russ: So, is your argument then that that was relatively unimportant? Guest: No, no. My argument is it can't explain why people who weren't generating these things and weren't going to be bailed out by us, investors in Norway, whatever--why were they buying? Russ: Well, I'm happy to admit that some people just made a mistake. After the fact. Ex ante they certainly didn't think they were throwing away their money. And a lot of those people making those investments around the world, we bailed them out, too. The European banks got some of the benefits. Guest: Yes, because they were mixed into the same piles that involved our own investment banks. And so they got bailed out in the process. If they were holding credit default swaps (CDSs) that were sold by AIG, they got bailed out. Russ: Although I think Goldman was the number 2 holder of those. The first was--I can't remember; it was a foreign bank, either French or German.
29:19Russ: So, you have publicly said that that was a mistake, those bailouts; we should have let them fail. Guest: It's irrelevant because there is no political regime that will let that happen. Russ: Correct. But let's suppose, let's live in a fantasy world for forty seconds. Suppose on March of 2008, Ben Bernanke and Hank Paulson and the others who got together to talk about the impending bankruptcy of Bear Stearns had just let them go. They would have opened for business Monday morning without enough cash to cover their positions; they would have had to tell their creditors: Sorry; I can't honor the promise I made to you the other day or the other money; and you won't be getting the payment you anticipated. The justification for the intervention was that if we had let that happen there would have been an enormous crisis: credit markets would have frozen up and we would have had a worldwide depression. Guest: I don't know about that last part. That's what we'll never know. The issue is: How long would it take to straighten things out? And I think it's really overrated that it would have taken a large amount of time. So, banks fail all the time, and the FDIC goes in and draws a line in the sand about who is going to get paid and who isn't; stuff is put up for sale and everything goes on. I don't know how long it would take to solve a multiple failure problem. We'll never know. Russ: Well, the Lehman Brother's bankruptcy is still in process. Which is now three years old. This was the argument made at the time--like you, I'm skeptical about it but it has some legitimacy--it's that bankruptcy is complicated enough as it is; when it's a large investment bank with international creditors like Bear, Lehman, it would take a long time. In the meanwhile everybody would be thrown into turmoil. Blah, blah, blah. Do you think there's anything to that? Guest: It's possible. What happened in the Lehman case is it's held up by multiple jurisdictions. So, you have to settle with the British shareholders. Russ: The Japanese, Korean. Guest: Who all have their own set of laws about what happens in a bankruptcy. And that's what I think they've been fighting over for three years. It's pretty clear what assets [?]. Russ: But isn't that an argument for justifying what Bernanke and Paulson did? Guest: I don't know. Because who knows what would have been done if all of them went down. The problem really is that the investment banks weren't subject to the same disposition rules that would face an ordinary commercial bank. They are not subject to the FDIC. And the FDIC can come in and arbitrarily do it. That's what you buy into when you sign up for it. Whereas for the investment banks, they are not really banks; and they are not subject to those rules. The ongoing problem is that you haven't killed their incentive to finance things the way they always have. Russ: Well, I guess my claim is that part of the problem is that we gave a regulatory advantage to triple-A rated stuff, which allowed very large and different amounts of leverage compared to other stuff. That gave an incentive to these folks to find more triple-A. The amount of triple-A is essentially, until recently, there's just not enough of it to go around, if that's the most profitable thing you can do, because that's the thing you can leverage; so they found a way to invent more of it. And that included not just the things we are talking about, but European sovereign debt. Hey, that's safe; let's leverage that, too. Guest: Right. Russ: So, once we said: this is the stuff that you can make scads of money on because you can leverage it and use other people's money. Guest: You are slipping back again, though. Russ: Because? Guest: You are saying that people will buy this stuff even though it isn't triple-A. Russ: Correct. Guest: Why? Russ: Well, that's the puzzle. Is it because they were stupid, ex ante? Guest: We are talking about the world's most sophisticated people who invest. Russ: So is the alternative argument that people just made a mistake? Guest: After the fact, definitely. Whether it was a mistake before the fact, that involves estimating the probabilities of extreme tail events, which, as you know, are very difficult. Russ: So, where does that leave us? Story-telling, of course. Guest: Which is very entertaining but it's not convincing. I don't find it convincing.
34:45Russ: Before I forget, I was going to ask you--I don't want to miss this chance to ask you this: Does your research inform your own personal portfolio decisions? And has it over time? Guest: Oh, sure, always. Russ: Has it changed over time? Guest: Well, I'm not as young as I used to be. Russ: That's part of the theory, too. Guest: Right. So, my portfolio has become somewhat more conservative. I'm also a stockholder in an investment management company, so that part of it is very unconservative. Russ: That's true. Recently--a related question to what we were just talking about before that--the government published the transcripts of the Federal Reserve deliberations in 2006. I don't know if you've looked at that. Guest: No. Russ: Well, one of the most obvious things you learn from reading those transcripts--well, first of all, this is 15 really smart people, very savvy. Their job is to try to figure out what could happen next that could be dangerous. And in 2006, we were on the edge of a collapse in the housing market. And as you argue, maybe just a general problem coming that would be unforeseeable. But what was interesting was that they made the same mistake that I made at the time; and I heard lots of other people much smarter than I am made the same mistake. They said: Well, it's true that there could be a housing price fall; it's been going up for a long time, but the subprimes are essentially only a small part of the whole housing market; housing is only a small part of the overall investment market. So, if this does occur, there's not going to be much of a consequence and we don't have to worry about it. Now, one of the things I think was mistaken, certainly for me as someone not very well versed in finance, and I think most economists are not very well versed in finance, is that we did not understand the role that leverage would play if asset prices fell by a relatively small amount. Do you think that has been a lesson that some people have learned from this crisis? And should we learn that lesson? Guest: Well, leverage will put some people out of business. Russ: Correct. Guest: So, what's the problem? Russ: Well, the problem is that if lots of people go out of business at the same time it allegedly has a multiplier effect--I hate to use that phrase--but that there is some credit market contagion, systemic risk, etc. Guest: That's a word I don't think existed 20 years ago. Russ: Which one? Guest: Systemic. Russ: But let's go back to our mutual friend, Milton. Certainly Milton would argue that the contraction of the money supply at the onset of the Great Depression precipitated by bank failures was something that the Federal Reserve should have paid attention to. Guest: What could they do? Russ: They should have injected liquidity into the system. Guest: Well, but if you have massive free reserves, what is that going to do? Russ: Well, that's a problem. Again, I wish Milton were here. I'm mystified by monetary policy generally, as anyone who has listened to these podcasts knows. Guest: Well, I am too. In the podcasts of this program that I've listened to, I've heard everybody talk about the Fed controlling the interest rates. That's always escaped me how they can do that. Russ: Yes, I'm mystified by it myself. Guest: But I'm in finance, so you've got an excuse. Russ: When I interviewed Milton in 2006 and I asked him why there had been a change in public discussion at least of what the Fed does from changing the money supply to instead manipulating interest rates, his answer was: Well, that's what they say but that's not what they do. They like to say they manipulate interest rates because it makes them feel powerful. All they really do is change the monetary base. And in fact he said, if you look at M2, that's the thing to look at. Guest: That's the thing to look at if you want to know what's happening to business activity. But it's not something you can do anything about.
39:28Russ: I'm with you there. While we're on that subject, do you have any thoughts on why the Fed is paying interest on reserves? Guest: Oh, absolutely. Because they know that if there is an opportunity cost from these massive reserves they've injected into the system, we are going to have a hyperinflation. Russ: So what's the point of injecting the reserves if you are going to keep them in the system? Guest: Exactly. Russ: So what's the answer? Guest: The answer is: this is just posturing. What's actually happened? That debt is now almost fully interest-bearing, all the liquidity that they've injected. So, they've actually made the problem of controlling inflation more difficult. Controlling inflation when they didn't pay any interest focused on the base: cash plus reserves. But now the reserves are interest-bearing, so they play no role in inflation. It all comes to cash, to currency. How do you know? Currency and reserves were completely interchangeable; that's what the Federal Reserve is all about. So I think they've lost it. Now what happened, they went and bought bonds, long-maturing bonds, and issued short-maturing bonds. It's nothing. They didn't do anything. Russ: But they are smart people. Guest: Right. Russ: Ben Bernanke is not a fool. If you could get him alone in a quiet place with nobody else listening and say: Ben, what were you thinking? What do you think he'd say? Guest: I don't know, but I wouldn't believe it. In the sense that at most he could have thought he could twist the yield curve. Lower the long-term bond rate. Now I'm looking at the long-term bond market--it's wide open. Even though they are doing big things, they are not that big relative to the size of the market. Russ: Yes, I am mystified by that as well. I don't have an explanation. Guest: Let me put it differently. So, if I look at the evolution of interest rates, is it credible that in the early 1980s the Fed wanted the short term interest rate to be 13-14%? Russ: No. You are making the argument that it's endogenous; that they can't control it. Guest: Maybe they can tweak it a bit; they can do a lot with inflationary expectations. That will affect interest rates. Turn it around--all international banks think they can control interest rates; and at the same time they agree that international bond markets are open. Inconsistent. Russ: Correct. It reminds of this CNN reporter, credible insight into economic policy. He said: Macroeconomics generally--and fiscal policy, but he could equally as well be talking about Central Bank policy--he said: Politicians who think they can control the economy are like a little kid who is playing a video game; he hasn't put the money in yet and he is watching the arcade game do all its bangs and bells and whistles and noises. Which is an advertisement for the game. And he's pushing the buttons, and he's attributing all the successes on the screen to himself even though he hasn't put the money in yet because he misunderstands the underlying process that generates what he is seeing on the screen. There is some truth to that. Guest: There's a lot of truth to it.
42:51Let's turn to fiscal policy, which you've written some interesting things on lately. You have been very skeptical, as have a few others. And by the way, I should add, before we get into this I should just mention: your view that it's an open question about whether the crisis was averted by these rather remarkable open interventions by the Fed and the Treasury Department in the last few years--it's not a mainstream view. Certainly most economists believe--and I'm with you--but most economists believe that the Fed and the Treasury and the policy makers did a good thing. Guest: That's not taking into account the long term costs. Russ: For sure. And that would be true of most of these interventions. I always find it remarkable that the auto bailout was a success, quote, "because very few people lost their jobs." As if that's the only effect we would ever want to look at. Guest: The long term effects of that are horrendous. Russ: And it's not clear that they saved very many jobs, either. Clearly they changed the incentives. Guest: Not just changed the incentives--they changed the ordering of precedence in contracts. That's something that's really dangerous. Russ: Yes, they abrogated the rule of law. It's very depressing. But on this issue of fiscal stimulus, most economists believe it's a good thing, it works. We are in the minority who suggest that maybe it isn't effective. And recently you wrote a piece suggesting, I would argue, that it's never effective--unless it's well-spent. And I would contrast it with the Keynesian view, which I heard come out of Joe Stiglitz's mouth personally--people can't be what they actually believe--I heard him actually say: It doesn't matter what you spend the money on; it's all stimulus. You are very much on the other side. So, explain why. Guest: When he says it doesn't matter what you spend the money on, I think he thinks there are multiple choices that would all be good. He doesn't think that if you just wash it down the sink, that's good. Russ: Oh, no; he said, when pressed and he was asked: If you ask people to dig ditches and fill them back in, would that stimulate the economy? And he said: Yes; but it's not as good as doing something productive. I can't explain it. It's a mystery to me. Guest: It's a mystery to me, too. Russ: But he's not on the show right now; I wish he were; I'll try to get him down the road. But in your view, talk about what you think the effect of stimulus is and why you are skeptical. Guest: This is a case where you can't be sure. If you look at the empirical evidence, it basically allows you to say anything you want, because the estimates of the effects of stimulus are subject to so much uncertainty. So, I think, though, if I interpreted Christina Romer's stuff properly, or she and her husband's stuff, what it says is that the only thing that clearly gets a pretty good statistical support is permanent [?]intervention [?]. And the other stuff is just [?]. I think that's probably--I'm an empiricist in the end, so that's probably, I don't know. I have my position that I think it's a waste of money, because it will all be wasted. Eventually, you have to finance it. You have to finance it now, which means eventually you have to pay back, future generations have to pay back, for things that are then mostly useless maybe. But the evidence doesn't, like you say. So it's possible for Stiglitz to say one thing; it's possible for you and I to say something entirely different. And neither one can point to the evidence. Russ: I don't view it as a very scientific enterprise. I view it as essentially ideology being wrapped up in scientism, scientific looking, statistical estimation. It seems to me there is too much noise. Guest: I don't agree with what you said when you started; I don't think most economists do think it works. Maybe I'm in the wrong cocoon. Russ: Yes, you need to get out more, Gene, I think. Although I'm in a different cocoon over here on the East Coast; I'm in the only cocoon, I'm at George Mason University and occasionally I'm at Stanford; so we just happen to talk about the three places where there is an overwhelming majority that is skeptical; but outside of those three, I think it's pretty much the other way. Guest: Well, Bob Barro.Russ: Lonely voice, in that enclave. Guest: I think with Barro, famous macroeconomist at Harvard, there's a younger guy. Russ: Alesina. Guest: Council of Economic Advisers. Russ: Oh, Mankiw. Guest: He's skeptical, but what he says is: Once you get into politics, you become a Keynesian. The political pressures are enormous. I think that's right. Russ: It's a terrible view of our intellectual opponents, though. It's not very nice. We don't like it when they attribute our views to being friends of business, which I find repugnant. So, it seems embarrassing to suggest that they hold their views because they like being powerful. I think there's some truth to it, but it's not very nice. You want to hold that view? Guest: Hold which view? I don't know. I don't think economists are different from other people. They all like, have their views, excepted [accepted?] by everybody else, no matter what their views are. Russ: We're prone to incentives; there's no doubt about that. Guest: I've had a tough time for a long time because I believe in efficient markets. Russ: Get a lot of flack.
49:13Russ: Let's go back to finance for a minute. I will put a link up to your recent article on stimulus where you make a theoretical argument against stimulus. Guest: There's no data, right. Russ: And I think basically--it's interesting how the Chicago school has been pushing this--you are using what I would call accounting identities. The money has got to come from somewhere. I expressed it as the resources have to come from somewhere. Guest: That's the right way to say it, actually. Russ: And so I don't understand where the free lunch comes from. Guest: There is no free lunch. Russ: But the counterpoint is that there is a free lunch because there are all these resources laying around. And then it's a question--Milton said this also--how much of the stimulus goes towards the unused, so-called-- Guest: But that's the problem of implementation, which is horrendous. The same problem in regulation: implementation, which is always the killer. Russ: But let's go back to finance. There's been a big trend in recent years towards what's called behavioral finance. What's your assessment of that? Guest: I think the behavioral people are very good at describing microeconomic behavior--the behavior of individuals--that doesn't seem quite rational. I think they are very good at that. The jump from there to markets is much more shaky. Russ: Explain. Guest: There are two types of behavioral economists. There are guys like my friend and colleague Richard Thaler, who are solidly based in psychology, reasoned economics but he's become a psychologist, basically, and he is coming from the research in psychology. Now there are other finance people who are basically what I call anomaly chasers. What they are doing is scouring the data for things that look like market inefficiency, and they classify that as behavioral finance. But to me it's just data judging [?]. Russ: They don't tell you about the times they can't find the anomaly. Guest: Exactly. In all economics research, there is a multiple comparisons problem that never gets stated. Russ: A multiple what? Guest: The fact that the data have been used by so many other people and the people using it now use it in so many different ways that they don't report, that you have no real statistical basis to evaluate and come to a conclusion. Russ: My view is you should video your keyboard so we can see your keystrokes and then we can see what didn't come out. The dishes that didn't come out of the kitchen because you didn't like the way they tasted. Guest: Right. I've had people say to me that the people who do this anomaly stuff, when they come and give a paper and I'll say, when you do this, that, or the other thing, and they'll say Yes. And I'll say, why don't you report it? And they'll say it wasn't interesting. Russ: Not publishable, either. Guest: Well, that's the problem, that there's a counting process [?] and a publication process as well. You do this, that, and the other thing and I'll say, yes, why don't you report it? And they say it wasn't interesting. Russ: It wasn't interesting. Not publishable, either. Guest: Well, that's the problem, there's a publishing process and a culling process as well. This stuff makes it through.
52:37Russ: So, we started off this conversation talking about efficient markets, and we haven't talked about a zillion other things that you've studied that are important in the field of finance. One question I'd like to hear you talk about is the issue of a non-specialist. Let's say I'm just a smart, everyday person and I want to be educated out in the world. What are the lessons for me that finance has learned that are important? There are obviously of findings that have stood up, findings that have had to be modified over the last 50 years that has become more empirical that an educated person should be able to understand and use? Guest: I'm obviously going to be biased. I think all of our stuff on efficient markets would qualify. I think there is a lot of stuff in the corporate area, corporate governance and all of that, a huge field--that has penetrated to the practical level. The Black-Scholes option pricing paper in view is the most important economics paper of the century. Russ: Why? Guest: Because every academic, every economist whether he went into finance or not, read that paper. And it created an industry. In the applied financial domain. What else can claim that? So, I think we've learned a lot about risk and return. Some of it is intuitive. But there is a lot of stuff on which stocks are more or less risky. A lot of stuff on international markets. Now, what should an ordinary, intelligent person know? That's an interesting question. Let me turn it over. What should an ordinary, intelligent person know about pricing? [More to come, 54:55]

Return to top

Source: http://www.econtalk.org/archives/2012/01/fama_on_finance.html

nhl realignment nhl realignment kristin chenoweth country music awards new earth light year light year